Production in the Short-run & Long-run
Production Functions
The production function relates the quantity of factor inputs used by a business to the amount of outputthat result. We use three measures of production and productivity.
The production function relates the quantity of factor inputs used by a business to the amount of outputthat result. We use three measures of production and productivity.
- Total product (or total output). In manufacturing industries such as motor vehicles and DVD players, it is straightforward to measure how much output is being produced. But in service or knowledge industries, where output is less “tangible” it is harder to measure productivity.
- Average product measures output per-worker-employed or output-per-unit of capital.
- Marginal product is the change in output from increasing the number of workers used by one person, or by adding one more machine to the production process in the short run.
The length of time required for the long run varies from sector to sector. In the nuclear power industry for example, it can take many years to commission new nuclear power plant and capacity. This is something the UK government has to consider as it reviews our future sources of energy.
Short Run Production Function
- The short run is a time period where at least one factor of production is in fixed supply. A business has chosen it’s scale of production and must stick with this in the short run
- We assume that the quantity of plant and machinery is fixed and that production can be altered by changing variable inputs such as labour, raw materials and energy.
- The time periods used differ from one industry to another; for example, the short-run in the electricity generation industry differs from local sandwich bars. If you are starting out in business with a new venture selling sandwiches and coffees to office workers, how long is your long run? It could be as short as a few days – enough time to lease a new van and a sandwich-making machine!
Diminishing Returns
- In the short run, the law of diminishing returns states that as we add more units of a variable inputto fixed amounts of land and capital, the change in total output will at first rise and then fall.
- Diminishing returns to labour occurs when marginal product of labour starts to fall. This means that total output will be increasing at a decreasing rate.
What might cause marginal product to fall? One explanation is that, beyond a certain point, new workers will not have as much capital equipment to work with so it becomes diluted among a larger workforce.
In the following numerical example, we assume that there is a fixed supply of capital (20 units) to which extra units of labour are added.
In the following numerical example, we assume that there is a fixed supply of capital (20 units) to which extra units of labour are added.
- Initially, marginal product is rising – e.g. the 4th worker adds 26 to output and the 5th worker adds 28 and the 6th worker increases output by 29.
- Marginal product then starts to fall. The 7th worker supplies 26 units and the 8th worker just 20 added units. At this point production demonstrates diminishing returns.
- Total output will continue to rise as long as marginal product is positive
- Average product will rise if marginal product > average product
The Law of Diminishing Returns
| ||||
Capital Input
|
Labour Input
|
Total Output
|
Marginal Product
|
Average Product of Labour
|
20
|
1
|
5
|
5
| |
20
|
2
|
16
|
11
|
8
|
20
|
3
|
30
|
14
|
10
|
20
|
4
|
56
|
26
|
14
|
20
|
5
|
85
|
28
|
17
|
20
|
6
|
114
|
29
|
19
|
20
|
7
|
140
|
26
|
20
|
20
|
8
|
160
|
20
|
20
|
20
|
9
|
171
|
11
|
19
|
20
|
10
|
180
|
9
|
18
|
Average product rises as long as marginal product is greater than the average – e.g. when the seventh worker is added the marginal gain in output is 26 and this drags the average up from 19 to 20 units. Once marginal product is below the average as it is with the ninth worker employed then the average must decline.
Criticisms of the Law of Diminishing Returns
- How realistic is this assumption of diminishing returns? Surely ambitious and successful businesses will do their level best to avoid such a problem emerging?
- It is now widely recognised that the effects of globalisation and the ability of trans-national businesses to source their inputs from more than one country and engage in transfers of business technology, makes diminishing returns less relevant as a concept.
- Many businesses are multi-plant meaning that they operate factories in different locations – they can switch output to meet changing demand.
Long Run Production - Returns to Scale
In the long run, all factors of production are variable. How the output of a business responds to a change in factor inputs is called returns to scale.
Numerical example of long run returns to scale | |||||
Units of Capital
|
Units of Labour
|
Total Output
|
% Change in Inputs
|
% Change in Output
|
Returns to Scale
|
20
|
150
|
3000
| |||
40
|
300
|
7500
|
100
|
150
|
Increasing
|
60
|
450
|
12000
|
50
|
60
|
Increasing
|
80
|
600
|
16000
|
33
|
33
|
Constant
|
100
|
750
|
18000
|
25
|
13
|
Decreasing
|
- When we double the factor inputs from (150L + 20K) to (300L + 40K) then the percentage change in output is 150% - there are increasing returns to scale.
- When the scale of production is changed from (600L + 80K0 to (750L + 100K) then the percentage change in output (13%) is less than the change in inputs (25%) implying a situation of decreasing returns to scale.
- Increasing returns to scale occur when the % change in output > % change in inputs
- Decreasing returns to scale occur when the % change in output < % change in inputs
- Constant returns to scale occur when the % change in output = % change in inputs
The nature of the returns to scale affects the shape of a business’s long run average cost curve.
Finding an optimal mix between labour and capital
In the long run businesses will be looking to find an output that combines labour and capital in a way that maximises productivity and therefore reduces unit costs towards their lowest level. This may involve a process of capital-labour substitution where capital machinery and new technology replaces some of the labour input.
In many industries over the years we have seen a rise in the capital intensity of production - good examples include farming, banking and retailing.
Robotic technology is extensively used in many manufacturing / assembly industries such as cars and semi-conductors. The image above is of a Ford car assembly factory in India.
No comments:
Post a Comment