Micro Economics

Production in the Short-run & Long-run

Production Functions
The production function relates the quantity of factor inputs used by a business to the amount of outputthat result. We use three measures of production and productivity.
  • Total product (or total output). In manufacturing industries such as motor vehicles and DVD players, it is straightforward to measure how much output is being produced. But in service or knowledge industries, where output is less “tangible” it is harder to measure productivity.
  • Average product measures output per-worker-employed or output-per-unit of capital.
  • Marginal product is the change in output from increasing the number of workers used by one person, or by adding one more machine to the production process in the short run.

The length of time required for the long run varies from sector to sector. In the nuclear power industry for example, it can take many years to commission new nuclear power plant and capacity. This is something the UK government has to consider as it reviews our future sources of energy.
Short Run Production Function
  • The short run is a time period where at least one factor of production is in fixed supply. A business has chosen it’s scale of production and must stick with this in the short run
  • We assume that the quantity of plant and machinery is fixed and that production can be altered by changing variable inputs such as labour, raw materials and energy.
  • The time periods used differ from one industry to another; for example, the short-run in the electricity generation industry differs from local sandwich bars. If you are starting out in business with a new venture selling sandwiches and coffees to office workers, how long is your long run? It could be as short as a few days – enough time to lease a new van and a sandwich-making machine!
Diminishing Returns
  • In the short run, the law of diminishing returns states that as we add more units of a variable inputto fixed amounts of land and capital, the change in total output will at first rise and then fall.
  • Diminishing returns to labour occurs when marginal product of labour starts to fall. This means that total output will be increasing at a decreasing rate.
What might cause marginal product to fall? One explanation is that, beyond a certain point, new workers will not have as much capital equipment to work with so it becomes diluted among a larger workforce.
In the following numerical example, we assume that there is a fixed supply of capital (20 units) to which extra units of labour are added.
  • Initially, marginal product is rising – e.g. the 4th worker adds 26 to output and the 5th worker adds 28 and the 6th worker increases output by 29.
  • Marginal product then starts to fall. The 7th worker supplies 26 units and the 8th worker just 20 added units. At this point production demonstrates diminishing returns.
  • Total output will continue to rise as long as marginal product is positive
  • Average product will rise if marginal product > average product
The Law of Diminishing Returns
Capital Input
Labour Input
Total Output
Marginal Product
Average Product of Labour
20
1
5

5
20
2
16
11
8
20
3
30
14
10
20
4
56
26
14
20
5
85
28
17
20
6
114
29
19
20
7
140
26
20
20
8
160
20
20
20
9
171
11
19
20
10
180
9
18
Average product rises as long as marginal product is greater than the average – e.g. when the seventh worker is added the marginal gain in output is 26 and this drags the average up from 19 to 20 units. Once marginal product is below the average as it is with the ninth worker employed then the average must decline.
Criticisms of the Law of Diminishing Returns
  • How realistic is this assumption of diminishing returns? Surely ambitious and successful businesses will do their level best to avoid such a problem emerging?
  • It is now widely recognised that the effects of globalisation and the ability of trans-national businesses to source their inputs from more than one country and engage in transfers of business technology, makes diminishing returns less relevant as a concept.
  • Many businesses are multi-plant meaning that they operate factories in different locations – they can switch output to meet changing demand.
Long Run Production - Returns to Scale
In the long run, all factors of production are variable. How the output of a business responds to a change in factor inputs is called returns to scale.

Numerical example of long run returns to scale
Units of Capital
Units of Labour
Total Output
% Change in Inputs
% Change in Output
Returns to Scale
20
150
3000



40
300
7500
100
150
Increasing
60
450
12000
50
60
Increasing
80
600
16000
33
33
Constant
100
750
18000
25
13
Decreasing
  • When we double the factor inputs from (150L + 20K) to (300L + 40K) then the percentage change in output is 150% - there are increasing returns to scale.
  • When the scale of production is changed from (600L + 80K0 to (750L + 100K) then the percentage change in output (13%) is less than the change in inputs (25%) implying a situation of decreasing returns to scale.
  • Increasing returns to scale occur when the % change in output > % change in inputs
  • Decreasing returns to scale occur when the % change in output < % change in inputs
  • Constant returns to scale occur when the % change in output = % change in inputs
The nature of the returns to scale affects the shape of a business’s long run average cost curve.
Finding an optimal mix between labour and capital
In the long run businesses will be looking to find an output that combines labour and capital in a way that maximises productivity and therefore reduces unit costs towards their lowest level. This may involve a process of capital-labour substitution where capital machinery and new technology replaces some of the labour input.
In many industries over the years we have seen a rise in the capital intensity of production - good examples include farming, banking and retailing.
Robotic technology is extensively used in many manufacturing / assembly industries such as cars and semi-conductors. The image above is of a Ford car assembly factory in India.



Calculating a Firm's Costs


In the short run, because at least one factor of production is fixed, output can be increased only by adding more variable factors. Hence we consider both fixed and variable costs
Fixed costs
Fixed costs are business expenses that do not vary directly with the level of output i.e. they are treated asindependent of the level of production.
Examples of fixed costs include the rental costs of buildings; the costs of leasing or purchasing capital equipment such as plant and machinery; the annual business rate charged by local authorities; the costs of full-time contracted salaried staff; the costs of meeting interest payments on loans; the depreciation of fixed capital (due solely to age) and also the costs of business insurance.
fixed costs

Fixed costs are the overhead costs of a business. They are important in markets where the fixed costs are high but the variable costs associated with making a small increase in output are relatively low. We will come back to this when we consider economies of scale.
  • Total fixed costs            (TFC)                remain constant as output increases
  • Average fixed cost          (AFC)    =          total fixed costs divided by output
Average fixed costs must fall continuously as output increases because total fixed costs are being spread over a higher level of production. In industries where the ratio of fixed to variable costs is extremely high, there is great scope for a business to exploit lower fixed costs per unit if it can produce at a big enough size.  Consider the new Sony portable play station. The fixed costs of developing the product are enormous, but these costs can be divided by millions of individual units sold across the world.
A change in fixed costs has no effect on marginal costs. Marginal costs relate only to variable costs!
Variable Costs
Variable costs are costs that vary directly with output. Examples of variable costs include the costs ofintermediate raw materials and other components, the wages of part-time staff or employees paid by the hour, the costs of electricity and gas and the depreciation of capital inputs due to wear and tear. Average variable cost (AVC) = total variable costs (TVC) /output (Q)
variable costs
Variable costs are those associated with changes in short run production – what are the variable costs associated with an increase in the production of Californian wine shown in the picture above?
Average Total Cost (ATC or AC)
Average total cost is simply the cost per unit produced
Average total cost (ATC) = total cost (TC) / output (Q)
Marginal Cost
Marginal cost is the change in total costs from increasing output by one extra unit.
The marginal cost of supplying an extra unit of output is linked with the marginal productivity of labour.The law of diminishing returns implies that the marginal cost of production will rise as output increases. Eventually, rising marginal cost will lead to a rise in average total cost. This happens when the rise in AVC is greater than the fall in AFC as output (Q) increases.
Worked example of short run production costs
A simple numerical example of short run costs is shown in the table below. Fixed costs are assumed to be constant at £200. Variable costs increase as more output is produced.

Output (Q)
Total Fixed Costs (TFC)
Total Variable Costs (TVC)
Total Cost
Average Cost Per Unit
Marginal Cost
(the change in total cost from a one unit change in output)
(TC= TFC + TVC)
(AC = TC/Q)
0
200
0
200


50
200
100
300
6
2
100
200
180
400
4
2
150
200
230
450
3
1
200
200
260
460
2.3
0.2
250
200
280
465
1.86
0.1
300
200
290
480
1.6
0.3
350
200
325
525
1.5
0.9
400
200
400
600
1.5
1.5
450
200
610
810
1.8
4.2
500
200
750
1050
2.1
4.8
In our example, average cost per unit is minimised at a range of output between 350 and 400 units. Thereafter, because the marginal cost of production exceeds the previous average, so the average cost rises (for example the marginal cost of each extra unit between 450 and 500 is 4.8 and this increase in output has the effect of raising the cost per unit from 1.8 to 2.1).
Short Run Cost Curves
When diminishing returns set in (beyond output Q1) the marginal cost curve starts to rise. Average total cost continues to fall until output Q2 where the rise in average variable cost equates with the fall in average fixed cost. Output Q2 is the lowest point of the ATC curve for this business in the short run. This is known as the output of productive efficiency.

short-run cost curve
A change in variable costs
A rise in the variable costs of production leads to an upward shift both in marginal and average total cost. The firm is not able to supply as much output at the same price. The effect is that of an inward shift in the supply curve of a business in a competitive market.
change in variable costs
An increase in fixed costs has no effect at all on variable costs of production. This means that only the average total cost curve shifts. There is no change at all on the marginal cost curve leading to no change in the profit maximising price and output of a business. The effects of an increase in the fixed or overhead costs of a business are shown in the diagram below.
change in variable costs

 

Long-run costs - economies & diseconomies of scale

Economies of Scale

  • In the long run all costs are variable and the scale of production can change (no fixed inputs)
  • Economies of scale are the cost advantages from expanding the scale of production in the long run. The effect is to reduce average costs over a range of output.
  • These lower costs represent an improvement in productive efficiency and can give a business acompetitive advantage in a market. They lead to lower prices and higher profits – this is called apositive sum game for producers and consumers (i.e. the welfare of both will improve)
  • We make no distinction between fixed and variable costs in the long run because all factors of production can be varied.
  • As long as the long run average total cost curve (LRAC) is declining, then internal economies of scale are being exploited. The table below shows a numerical example of falling LRAC
Long Run Output (Units)
Total Costs (£s)
Long Run Average Cost (£ per unit)
1000
12000
12
2000
20000
10
5000
45000
9
10000
80000
8
20000
144000
7.2
50000
330000
6.6
100000
640000
6.4
500000
3000000
6

Returns to Scale and Costs in the Long Run
The table below shows how changes in the scale of production can, if increasing returns to scale are exploited, lead to lower long run average costs.
Factor Inputs
Production
Costs
(K)
(La)
(L)
(Q)

(TC)
(TC/Q)
Capital
Land
Labour
Output

Total Cost
Average Cost
Scale A
5
3
4
100

3256
32.6
Scale B
10
6
8
300

6512
21.7
Scale C
15
9
12
500

9768
19.5
Costs: Assume the cost of each unit of capital = £600, Land = £80 and Labour = £200
Because the % change in output exceeds the % change in factor inputs used, then, although total costs rise, the average cost per unit falls as the business expands from scale A to B to C.
Increasing Returns to Scale
Much of the new thinking in economics focuses on the increasing returns available to a company growing in size in the long run.
An example of this is the software business.
  • The overhead costs of developing new software programs or computer games are huge - often running into hundreds of millions of dollars
  • But the marginal cost of one extra copy for sale is close to zero, perhaps just a few cents or pennies.
  • If a company can establish itself in the market, positive feedback from consumers will expand the installed customer base, raise demand and encourage the firm to increase production.
  • Because marginal cost is so low, the extra output reduces average costs creating economies of size.
Capacity utilisation, fixed costs and profits
Lower costs normally mean higher profits and increasing financial returns for the shareholders. What is true for software developers is also important for telecoms companies, transport operators and music distributors.
We find across many different markets that, when a high percentage of costs are fixed the higher the level of production the lower will be the average cost of production. Strong demand means that capacity utilization rates are high and this lowers the unit cost of supply.

Long Run Average Cost Curve

The long run average cost curve (LRAC) is known as the ‘envelope curve’ and is usually drawn on the assumption of their being an infinite number of plant sizes – hence its smooth appearance in the next diagram below.
The points of tangency between LRAC and SRAC curves do not occur at the minimum points of the SRAC curves except at the point where the minimum efficient scale (MES) is achieved.
If LRAC is falling when output is increasing then the firm is experiencing economies of scale.  For example a doubling of factor inputs might lead to a more than doubling of output.
Conversely, When LRAC eventually starts to rise then the firm experiences diseconomies of scale, and, If LRAC is constant, then the firm is experiencing constant returns to scale
The working assumption is that a business will choose the least-cost method of production in the long run. Moving down the LRAC means there are cost advantages from a bigger scale of operations.
The Long Run Average Cost Curve (LRAC)

Sources of Internal Economies of Scale (IEoS)

Internal economies of scale come from the long-term growth of the firm. Examples include:
  1. Technical economies of scale:
These refer to gains in productivity from scaling up production.
    1. Expensive (indivisible) capital inputs: Large-scale businesses can afford to invest in specialist capital machinery. For example, a supermarket might invest in database technology that improves stock control and reduces transportation and distribution costs.
    2. Specialization of the workforce: Larger firms can split the production processes into separate tasks to boost productivity. Examples include the use of division of labour in the mass production of motor vehicles and in manufacturing electronic products.
    3. The law of increased dimensions (also known as the “container principle”) This is linked to the cubic law where doubling the height and width of a tanker or building leads to a more than proportionate increase in the cubic capacity
    1. The application of this law opens up the possibility of scale economies in distribution andfreight industries and also in travel and leisure sectors with the emergence of super-cruisers such as P&O’s Ventura. Consider the new generation of super-tankers and the development of enormous passenger aircraft such as the Airbus 280 which is capable of carrying over 500 passengers on long haul flights.
    2. The law of increased dimensions is also important in the energy sectors and in industries such as office rental and warehousing. Amazon for example has invested in several huge warehouses at its central distribution points – capable of storing hundreds of thousands of items.
    1. Learning by doing: The average costs of production decline in real terms as a result of production experience as businesses cut waste and find the most productive means of producing output on a bigger scale. Evidence across a wide range of industries into so-calledprogress ratios”, or “experience curves”, indicate that unit manufacturing costs typically fall by between 70% and 90% with each doubling of cumulative output.
  1. Marketing Economies - Monopsony Power: A large firm can purchase its factor inputs in bulk at discounted prices if it has monopsony (buying) power. A good example would be the ability of the electricity generators to negotiate lower prices when finalizing coal and gas supply contracts. The national food retailers have monopsony power when purchasing their supplies from farmers and wine growers and in completing supply contracts from food processing businesses. Other controversial examples of the use of monopsony power include the prices paid by coffee roasters and other middlemen to coffee producers in some of the poorest parts of the world.
  2. Managerial economies of scale: This is a form of division of labour where firms can employ specialists to supervise production systems. Better management; increased investment in human resources and the use of specialist equipment, such as networked computers can improve communication, raise productivity and thereby reduce unit costs.
  3. Financial economies of scale: Larger firms are usually rated by the financial markets to be more‘credit worthy’ and have access to credit with favourable rates of borrowing. In contrast, smaller firms often pay higher rates of interest on overdrafts and loans. Businesses quoted on the stock market can normally raise new financial capital more cheaply through the sale of equities to the capital market. The credit crunch and fragility of the banking system has made raising finance harder for businesses of all sizes – bank overdraft and loan interest rates have increased across the board, but it remains true that larger corporations can still access credit at a cheaper cost.
  4. Network economies of scale: There is growing interest in the concept of a network economy. Some networks and services have huge potential for economies of scale. That is, as they are more widely used (or adopted), they become more valuable to the business that provides them.
Case Study: Small businesses and financial economies of scale
A Bank of England survey on financial and credit conditions finds that smaller businesses are finding it tough to get the credit they need to finance an upturn in sales and production.
Interest rate spreads on new loans are rising and it is larger firms that seem to be benefitting from lower borrowing costs. According to the report “larger businesses are enjoying a reduction in the cost of borrowing and improved access to credit as banks favour lower-risk custom.”
The main commercial banks continue to adopt a risk-averse approach to new lending and this may hamper prospects of recovery. Unsecured loans for consumers have also become harder to get and more expensive despite the ultra-low interest rate policy of the Bank of England. In 2006, the top 10 average rate for a £3,000 personal loan was 6.49%, but today it is 14.92%, analysis by price comparison website moneysupermarket.com has shown.   Source: Tutor2u economics blog, April 2010

What are Network Economies of Scale?
The power of networks is becoming increasingly recognized in the economics of long run costs, revenues and profits.
Many networks have huge potential for economies of scale. That is, as they are more widely used (or adopted), they become more valuable to the business that provides them.
Good examples to use include online auction sites such as eBay, social networking sites, wireless service providers, air and rail transport networks and businesses such as Amazon.
In most cases, the marginal cost of adding one more user or customer to a network is close to zero, but the resulting financial benefits may be huge because each new user to the network can then interact, trade with all of the existing members or parts of the network.
Given the high fixed costs of establishing a network, the more users there are the lower are the fixed costs per unit. Thus as the network expands, not only are there potential gains from extra revenues, but the long run cost per user diminishes - an internal economy of scale.
In some cases an industry that requires a network to fulfill customer needs and wants across a country or region might be classified as a natural monopoly - an industry where long run average cost falls over a huge range of output and where the minimum efficient scale is a large percentage of market demand.
Consider as examples the networks required by the major utilities such as water, gas, electricity and (fixed line) broadband suppliers. And perhaps businesses such as Network Rail and the Royal Mail might also claim to have aspects of a natural monopoly given the requirement for the former to maintain and improve a national rail infrastructure and, for the latter, to keep a universal postal service running to add postal addresses in the country - this is of course a loss-making aspect of their business model.
Where there are strong grounds for believing an industry is a natural monopoly, there might be a case for nationalizing and/or regulating the network element of the business but introducing competition into the actual service provision - e.g. franchise bids for train operating companies, and partial or complete deregulation of parcel and letter collection, sorting and delivery.
Source: Tutor2u Economics Blog
Analysis: Economies of Scale – Effects on Price, Output and Profits
Consider the diagram:
  • Scale economies allow a supplier to move from SRAC1 to SRAC2
  • A profit maximizing producer will produce at a higher output (Q2) and charge a lower price (P2) as a result – but the total profit is also much higher (compare the two shaded regions)
  • Both consumer and producer surplus has increased – there has been an improvement in economic welfare and efficiency – the key is whether cost savings are passed onto consumers!
Analysis Diagram for External Economies of Scale (EEoS)
  • External economies of scale occur outside of a firm but within an industry.
  • For example investment in a better transportation network servicing an industry will resulting in a decrease in costs for a company working within that industry.
  • Another example is the development of research and development facilities in local universitiesthat several businesses in an area can benefit from.
  • Likewise, the relocation of component suppliers and other support businesses close to the centre of manufacturing are also an external cost saving.
  • Agglomeration economies may also result from the clustering of businesses in a distinct geographical location e.g. software in Silicon Valley or investment banks in the City of London

Economies of Scale – The Importance of Market Demand

The market structure of an industry is affected by the extent of economies of scale available to individual suppliers and by the total size of market demand.
  • In many industries, it is possible for smaller firms to make a profit because the cost disadvantages they face are relatively small. Or because product differentiation allows a business to charge a price premium to consumers which more than covers their higher costs.
  • A good example is the retail market for furniture. The industry has major players in different segments (e.g. flat-pack and designer furniture) including the Swedish giant IKEA. However, much of the market is taken by smaller-scale suppliers with consumers willing to pay higher prices for bespoke furniture owing to the low price elasticity of demand for high-quality, hand crafted furniture products.
  • Small-scale manufacturers can extract the consumer surplus that is present when demand is estimated to have a low elasticity of demand.

Economies of Scope

  • Economies of scope occur where it is cheaper to produce a range of products rather than specialize in just a handful of products.
For example, in the competitive world of postal services and business logistics, service providers such as Royal Mail, UK Mail, Deutsche Post and parcel carriers including TNT, UPS, and FedEx are broadening the range of their services and making better use of their collection, sorting and distribution networks to reduce costs and earn higher profits from higher-profit-margin and fast growing markets.
  • A company’s management structureadministration systems and marketing departments are capable of carrying out these functions for more than one product.
  • Expanding the product range to exploit the value of existing brands is a good way of exploiting economies of scope.
  •  A good example of “brand extension” is the Easy Group under the control of Stelios where the distinctive Easy Group business model has been applied (with varying degrees of success) to a wide range of markets – easy Pizza, easy Cinema, easy Car rental, easy Bus and easy Hotel to name just a handful!
  • Procter and Gamble is the largest consumer household products maker in the world. Its brands include Crest, Duracell, Gillette, Pantene, and Tide, to name just a few. Twenty four of its brands make over $1 billion in sales annually.
Another example of an economy of scope might be a restaurant that has catering facilities and uses it for multiple occasions – as a coffee shop during the day and as a supper-bar and jazz room in the evenings.
A computing business can use its network and databases for many different uses.

Long Run Costs – Importance of Minimum Efficient Scale (MES)

  • The minimum efficient scale (MES) is the scale of output where the internal economies of scale have been fully exploited.
  • MES corresponds to the lowest point on the long run average cost curve and is also known as an output range over which a business achieves productive efficiency.
  • MES is not a single output level – more likely, the MES is a range of outputs where the firm achievesconstant returns to scale and has reached the lowest feasible cost per unit.

The minimum efficient scale depends on the nature of costs of production in a specific industry.
How many firms can "fit" in a market?  It depends on the size of the market compared to the size of the minimum efficient scale
In industries where the ratio of fixed to variable costs is high, there is scope for reducing unit cost by increasing the scale of output. This is likely to result in a concentrated market structure (e.g. an oligopoly, a duopoly or a monopoly) – indeed economies of scale may act as a barrier to entry because existing firms have achieved cost advantages and they then can force prices down in the event of new businesses coming in
There might be only limited opportunities for scale economies such that the MES turns out to be a small % of market demand. It is likely that the market will be competitive with many suppliers able to achieve the MES. An example might be a large number of hotels in a city centre or a cluster of restaurants in a town. Much depends on how we define the market!
With a natural monopoly, the long run average cost curve continues to fall over a huge range of output, suggesting that there may be room for perhaps one or two suppliers to fully exploit all of the available economies of scale when meeting market demand.

Diseconomies of scale

Nokia, diseconomies of scale and lost competitive advantage
Nokia is a Finnish conglomerate business that turned itself into the world’s leading mobile phone company in the 1990s. Nokia is profitable, but revenues are under pressure and in 2010, Nokia appointed a new CEO - Stephen Elop - to drive strategic change
In February 2011 - Elop issued the famous “burning platform” memo bluntly explaining the strategic challenges facing Nokia. Elop announced a strategic partnership with Microsoft to jointly-develop smart phones using the Windows mobile platform - ditching Nokia’s investment in its homegrown Symbian platform
Nokia had missed the major change in its market - the Smartphone revolution. It had continued to focus on mobile phone devices (hardware) rather than applications (software). The consumer transition from traditional mobile phones to smart phones has been dramatic and caught Nokia off-guard. According to Elop "There is intense heat coming from our competitors, more rapidly than we ever expected. Apple disrupted the market by redefining the Smartphone and attracting developers to a closed, but powerful ecosystem.”
Nokia has also faced intense competition from mobile phone producers in emerging markets who can make fast, cheap handset. At the same time there was recognition within the business that diseconomies of scale were hurting its competitiveness. Many in Nokia regretted that the business had become too product-led rather than customer-led. It was felt that the business lacked innovation with an overly-bureaucratic organisational structure with poor accountability.
Diseconomies are the result of decreasing returns to scale and lead to a rise in average cost
Diseconomies of scale a business may experience relate to:
  1. Control – monitoring the productivity and the quality of output from thousands of employees in big corporations is imperfect and expensive – this links to the concept of the principal-agent problemi.e. the difficulties of shareholders monitoring the performance of managers.
  2. Co-ordination - it can be difficult to co-ordinate complicated production processes across several plants in different locations and countries. Achieving efficient flows of information in large businesses is expensive as is the cost of managing supply contracts with hundreds of suppliers at different points of an industry’s supply chain.
  3. Co-operation - workers in large firms may develop a sense of alienation and loss of morale. If they do not consider themselves to be an integral part of the business, their productivity may fall leading to wastage of factor inputs and higher costs. Traditionally this has been seen as a problem experienced by the larger state sector businesses, examples being the Royal Mail and theFirefighters, the result being a poor and costly industrial relations performance. However, the problem is not concentrated solely in such industries. A good recent example of a bitter industrial relations dispute was between Gate Gourmet and its workers.
Avoiding diseconomies of scale
Here are three of the reasons to doubt the persistence of diseconomies of scale:
  1. Human resource management (HRM) focuses on improvements in recruitment, training, promotion, retention and support of faculty and staff. This becomes critical to a business when the skilled workers it needs are in short supply.
  2. Performance related pay schemes (PRP) can provide financial incentives for the workforce leading to an improvement in industrial relations and higher productivity. Another aim of PRP is for businesses to reward and hang onto their most efficient workers. The John Lewis Partnership is often cited as an example of how a business can empower its employees by giving them a stake in the financial success of the organization.
  3. Increasingly companies are engaging in out-sourcing of manufacturing and distribution as they seek to supply to ever-distant markets. Out-sourcing is a tried and tested way of reducing costs whilst retaining control over production although there may be a price to pay in terms of the impact on the job security of workers whose functions might be outsourced overseas.




4 comments:

  1. Emergency Cash Loans Hello Everybody, My name is Mrs. Phyllis Sue South. I live in UK London and i am a happy woman today? and i told my self that any lender that rescue my family from our poor situation, i will refer any person that is looking for loan to him, he gave me happiness to me and my family, i was in need of a loan of $350,000.00 to start my life all over as i am a single mother with 2 kids I met this honest and GOD fearing man loan lender that help me with a loan of $350,000.00 U.S. Dollar, he is a GOD fearing man, if you are in need of loan and you will pay back the loan please contact him tell him that is Mrs. Phyllis Sue South that refer you to him. contact Dr. James Eric via email: financialserviceoffer876@gmail.com Whats-App +918929509036

    ReplyDelete
  2. HEARTLAND LOAN FIRM
    HEAD OFFICE --52, South Campbell Springfield UNITED KINGDOM
    E-MAIL ADDRESS - {heartlandloancenter4@gmail.com}

    -*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-**-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*
    You are welcome to HEARTLAND LOAN FIRM ,our obligation is
    helping the needy to gain financial stability in order to meet with the demands of living.
    And helping those who are in financial crises.

    We give out loans from the range of $1,000 to $90,000,000.Our loans
    are well insured and maximum security is our priority,at an interest
    of 1.2% rate.

    We give out our Loan in USD($) and GBP(£) and any currency of your choice.


    * Project Loans
    * Personal loans
    * Debt consolidation loans
    * Car Loans
    * Business loans
    * Education loans
    * Mortgage loans
    * Refinance loans
    * Home loans

    -*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*

    * Are you financially Squeezed?
    * Do you seek funds to pay off credits and debts
    * Do you seek finance to set up your own business?
    * Are you in need of private or business loan for various purposes?
    * Do you seek loan to carry out large projects
    * Do you seek funding for various other

    if you need loan you can contact us via our email address—{heartlandloancenter4@gmail.com}

    -*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-*-**-*-


    Get affordable Loan from HEARTLAND LOAN FIRM .

    LOAN BENEFIT
    *Available 24hours/7days
    *Loan is offer to individual/corporate worldwide
    *No Collateral Required.
    *Interest Rate of 1.2%.
    *Loan Amount: $1000 USD and above.
    *Loan Repayment Schedule Start 8 months after.
    *Loan Repayment Grace Period of 8 months.

    *Payment is made to applicant via

    Wire Transfer (E-Banking) (20 minutes)
    Bank to bank transfer (2 hours)
    Western union or money gram (5 minutes)



    THANKS
    CHARLENE TAYLOR
    {heartlandloancenter4@gmail.com}
    www.heartlandloan.webs.com
    HEARTLAND LOAN FIRM



    ReplyDelete
  3. QUICK EASY EMERGENCY URGENT LOANS LOAN OFFER EVERYONE APPLY NOW +918929509036 financialserviceoffer876@gmail.com Dr. James Eric

    ReplyDelete